首页> 外文期刊>International journal of sustainable development >Climate cooperation as development policy: the case of Costa Rica
【24h】

Climate cooperation as development policy: the case of Costa Rica

机译:气候合作作为发展政策:哥斯达黎加的情况

获取原文
获取原文并翻译 | 示例
       

摘要

Project-based climate cooperation between industrial and developing countries was first proposed in the early 1990s, then under the name of joint implementation (JI). Once in place, this cooperation could lead to a high amount of additional financial flows to developing countries. Nevertheless, many NGOs and developing country representatives were in the beginning very sceptical about JI and feared it would not take into account development priorities and create new kinds of dependence on industrial countries. Therefore, developing countries and industrial countries found compromise at the Berlin Conference of the Parties as they instituted a pilot phaser for so-called activities implemented jointly (AIJ), lasting until 2000. Since the Kyoto conference, this concept has existed in the design of the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), Which allows for industrialized countries to account this kind of activity against their national obligation for greenhouse gas reduction, starting with the year 2000. This paper discusses the first results of the AIJ pilot phase in Costa Rica, which is important for the evaluation of the whole pilot phase and the ultimate design of the CDM. Costa Rica has a relatively high level of economic and social development and a well-developed environmental policy, which is comparable with that of advanced industrial countries. It is a major destination for ecotourism. Nevertheless, it suffers from high deforestation, owing to unequal distribution of land, migration and cattle ranching, as well as plantation expansion. Moreover, transport emissions are rising rapidly and fossil fuel electricity generation is growing, despite a target of phasing out fossil fuels completely. Building on a broad knowledge base. Costa Rica was able to develop creative environmental policy instruments, such as debt-for-nature swaps and biodiversity prospecting, to attract foreign funding. It is not surprising that it was the first developing country to open a JI office, develop project approval criteria and host AIJ pilot projects. The framework for climate cooperation in Costa Rica can therefore be described as ideal compared with the average developing country. After an initial phase of single bilateral projects, the Costa Rican JI office tried to attract more finance by offering certified tradeable carbon certificates resulting form these projects' offsets. Now it encourages multi-sector large-scale programmes, where transaction costs are lower and coherence with national development objective can be more easily checked. It directs its attention to public AIJ investors, such as the Norwegian government. The renewable energy projects suffer from the unrealistic target to phase out fossil fuels by 2001, thus making AIJ projects in this sector impossible from that time. Therefore, the bulk of projects concerns forestry, which is prone to uncertainties in the calculation of emission sequestration. A comparison of the estimates shows wildly differing assumptions in baselines and the sequestration capacity of the forests. Whether actual project implementation conforms to the plans remains to be seen. The analysis of the Costa Rican case shows that climate cooperation can be successful in the long run only if the industrial countries offer incentives for investors and if baseline determination rests on a clear set of guidelines. Human and technical capacities are necessary but not sufficient conditions for successful climate cooperation projects in developing countries. They seem to be able to prevent complete project failures, however, and can lead to innovative approaches. The issue will be settled only if large-scale investment is forthcoming under a regime of legally binding emission targets for industrial countries, as stipulated in the Kyoto Protocol. Then the ability to process a huge number of project proposals and to check whether they conform to development priorities, as well as monitoring and verification, becomes cruci
机译:工业与发展中国家之间基于项目的气候合作最初是在1990年代初提出的,然后以联合实施(JI)的名义提出。一旦建立起来,这种合作将导致大量额外的资金流向发展中国家。然而,许多非政府组织和发展中国家代表在一开始对联合执行感到非常怀疑,并担心联合执行不会考虑发展优先事项并造成对工业国家的新依赖。因此,发展中国家和工业国家在柏林缔约方会议上建立了一个试点阶段,以进行所谓的联合执行活动(AIJ),一直持续到2000年。在京都会议之后,这一概念就一直存在。清洁发展机制(CDM),该机制使工业化国家可以从2000年开始,针对国家减少温室气体的义务对此类活动进行核算。本文讨论了哥斯达黎加AIJ试点阶段的初步结果,对于评估整个试点阶段和CDM的最终设计非常重要。哥斯达黎加的经济和社会发展水平较高,并且制定了与发达工业国家相当的环境政策。这是生态旅游的主要目的地。然而,由于土地分配不均,移民和牲畜放牧以及人工林扩张,它遭受了严重的森林砍伐。此外,尽管目标是完全淘汰化石燃料,但运输排放量迅速增加,化石燃料发电量也在增长。建立在广泛的知识基础上。哥斯达黎加能够开发创新的环境政策工具,例如以债务换自然和寻找生物多样性,以吸引外国资金。毫不奇怪,它是第一个开设联合执行办公室,制定项目批准标准并主持AIJ试点项目的发展中国家。因此,与一般发展中国家相比,哥斯达黎加的气候合作框架可以说是理想的。在单个双边项目的初始阶段之后,哥斯达黎加联合酋长国办事处试图通过提供由这些项目抵消产生的可交易碳证书来吸引更多资金。现在,它鼓励实行多部门的大型计划,在这些计划中,交易费用较低,可以更容易地检查与国家发展目标的一致性。它将注意力集中在公共AIJ投资者上,例如挪威政府。可再生能源项目遭受了到2001年逐步淘汰化石燃料的不切实际的目标,因此从那时起该领域的AIJ项目就不可能了。因此,大部分项目都与林业有关,这在排放固存的计算中容易出现不确定性。对估计值的比较表明,在基准和森林封存能力方面的假设存在很大差异。实际的项目实施是否符合计划仍有待观察。对哥斯达黎加案例的分析表明,只有工业化国家为投资者提供激励措施,并且基线确定以一套明确的准则为基础,气候合作才能长期成功。要在发展中国家成功开展气候合作项目,必须具备人力和技术能力,但不是充分条件。但是,它们似乎可以防止整个项目失败,并且可以带来创新的方法。只有按照《京都议定书》的规定,在具有法律约束力的工业化国家排放目标制度下进行大规模投资,这一问题才能得到解决。然后,处理大量项目建议并检查它们是否符合开发优先级以及进行监视和验证的能力变得至关重要。

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号