...
首页> 外文期刊>Industrial and Corporate Change >Response to Kay:'chandlerism in post-war Europe: strategic and structural change in France, Germany and the united kingdom, 1950-1993: a comment
【24h】

Response to Kay:'chandlerism in post-war Europe: strategic and structural change in France, Germany and the united kingdom, 1950-1993: a comment

机译:对凯的回应:“战后欧洲的狂热主义:法国,德国和英国的战略和结构变革,1950-1993年:评论

获取原文
获取原文并翻译 | 示例
           

摘要

Kay (2002) offers the following subtitle to his comment: 'The curious case of the persistent conglomerate'. It is a good choice. His analysis of both American and our own European data suggests a persistence with conglomerate diversification strategies that is surprising to orthodox interpretations of the resource-based view of the firm. He points out that the strategic stability we found amongst our European related diversifiers (Whittington et al., 1999) may be exaggerated by a broad categorization that obscures instability around the more finely defined related-constrained and related-linked diversification strategies. Kay (2002) argues too that unrelated conglomerate strategies may be more persistent than usually recognized partly because of their attractions as hedges against technological risk. He therefore invites us to reanalyse strategic persistence amongst our large European firms both according to different strategy categories and in the light of sectoral variations in technological intensity. This is an invitation worth pursuing. Conglomerates remain a substantial phenomenon empirically, accounting for about one-fifth of large American firms in the 1980s (Markides, 1996) and a quarter of large European firms in the 1990s (Whittington et al., 1999). They are also challenging theoretically, contradicting dominant understandings of the resource-based view. Conglomerates are both too important and too challenging to leave as simply 'curious'. The reanalysis that follows reveals a persistence to conglomerate strategies in line with the kind of re-evaluation that Kay (2002) is calling for. However, contrary to Kay (1982, 2002), these conglomerate strategies turn out not to be particularly concentrated in technologically risky sectors--rather the reverse. We shall offer an alternative explanation that extends the orthodox resource-based view both by emphasizing the value of corporate managerial resources and by allowing for headquarter costs. Conglomerates survive because they achieve a balance between headquarter costs and corporate value creation that is equivalent to that of related-constrained diversifiers and superior to that of related-linked diversifiers.
机译:凯(2002)为他的评论提供了以下副标题:“持续存在的集团的奇怪案例”。这是一个不错的选择。他对美国和我们自己的欧洲数据的分析表明,企业集团的多元化战略仍然存在,这对正统解释企业基于资源的观点感到惊讶。他指出,我们在欧洲相关的多元化企业中发现的战略稳定性(Whittington等人,1999)可能被广泛的分类夸大了,这种分类掩盖了围绕更精细定义的相关受限和相关联的多元化战略的不稳定性。 Kay(2002)也认为,不相关的集团战略可能比通常公认的战略更具持久性,部分原因是它们的吸引力在于对冲技术风险。因此,他邀请我们根据不同的战略类别并根据技术强度的部门差异,重新分析欧洲大型公司之间的战略持久性。这是值得追求的邀请。从经验上看,大企业集团仍然是一个重大现象,在1980年代约占美国大型企业的五分之一(Markides,1996),在1990年代约占欧洲大型企业的四分之一(Whittington等,1999)。他们还在理论上提出挑战,与对基于资源的观点的主流理解相矛盾。大型企业集团既重要又充满挑战,以至于不能简单地“好奇”地离开。随后的重新分析揭示了集团战略的持久性,这与Kay(2002)要求的那种重新评估相一致。但是,与凯(1982,2002)相反,这些联合企业战略并未特别集中在技术风险较高的行业,反之亦然。我们将提供另一种解释,通过强调公司管理资源的价值和考虑总部成本来扩展基于正统资源的观点。大型企业之所以能够生存,是因为它们在总部成本和企业价值创造之间取得了平衡,该平衡与相关约束的多元化企业的利润相等,并且优于相关链接的多元化企业的价值。

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号