首页> 外文期刊>Journal of Law and the Biosciences >The regulation of cognitive enhancement devices: refining Maslen et?al.'s model
【24h】

The regulation of cognitive enhancement devices: refining Maslen et?al.'s model

机译:认知增强设备的调节:完善Maslen等人的模型

获取原文
           

摘要

De Ridder, Vanneste, and Focquaert address concerns relating to the definition of a CED and the distinction between treatment and enhancement.1 They raise a number of problems with the treatment-enhancement distinction and suggest that we need to ask ‘whether we are prepared to change the definition of health used by the Medical Devices Directive'. There are in fact three questions raised here. The first is whether our proposal requires a robust characterization of the treatment-enhancement distinction, the second is whether our suggestions, as we intended them, actually involve changing the definition of heath implicit in the MDD (there is no explicit definition), and the third is whether the mere inclusion of CEDs within the MDD will have the de facto effect of changing the implicit regulatory concept of ‘health' or ‘treatment'. Fitz and Reiner broadly support our proposals and endorse our central claim, viz. that the regulatory framework for medical devices should be extended to include CEDs.12 Nevertheless, they raise a concern about the ability of CED users to evaluate the risks of CEDs, saying that ‘evidence that consumers are in a strong position to evaluate the risks associated with CED use is lacking' (p. 323). Johnson, Gillett, and Snelling suggest that the most convincing argument in favor of our position is based on the regulatory assessment of risk, which they believe should be the sole consideration in pre-market assessment.14 We suggest here that our respective proposals are not as different as they may have seemed, as we proposed that risk should be the primary regulatory concern. However, we diverge from the position advocated by them in our contention that objective improvements to cognitive capacities are amenable and relevant to assessment. Further to their concerns regarding individuals' abilities to weigh risks, Fitz and Reiner emphasize the remaining problem of ‘do-it-yourself' (DIY) users who, in constructing devices from scratch, will be afforded no protection by the regulation of direct-to-consumer devices. One of their proposals, with which we agree, is to bolster our recommendations with additional attempts at ‘active harm reduction'.18 They suggest that members of the professional community could join together to create an ‘inclusive online community', where information could be gathered and disseminated with professional oversight. We are broadly sympathetic with much of what they propose and would support the creation of an inclusive online community, were there to be sufficient expert interest in creating and maintaining it. Indeed, we are currently exploring how expert advice could be dispensed via existing fora, such as Reddit.19De Ridder, Vanneste, and Focquaert raise the concern that the societal benefits of enhancement might be lost if devices are in fact effective but regulated. In relation to this, we emphasize that the regulation we advocate is not akin to prohibition. To the extent that our proposals would prevent devices from being placed on the market, this would be limited to very dangerous devices or devices making implausible claims—hardly the sorts of devices that would confer net societal benefits. The important point that many other commentators on our model appear to overlook is that the effectiveness of brain stimulation techniques as a type of intervention does not guarantee the effectiveness of particular token devices claiming to be of this effective type. Regulation would assess devices at this case-by-case level. De Ridder, Vanneste, and Focquaert raise concerns about the misuse of resources, which assumes a position markedly different from that which we set out in our paper. They argue, persuasively, that resources should be directed to the most important causes and that enhancements might not be of a high enough priority to warrant use of our limited resources. We agree that limited resources need to be allocated carefully, but our proposal does not threaten such allocation: the devices that would be prohibited under our proposal are ones that would certainly not warrant significant investment of public resources, and our proposal leaves open how resources should be allocated among those that would be permitted. Perhaps De Ridder and collaborators assumed us to be advocating the inclusion of CEDs under the healthcare funding arrangements, but this is not what we envisaged. The extension to the scope of the MDD, as we recommend it, has no direct implications for the distribution of healthcare resources. Relatedly, the authors ask whether the regulation of CEDs requires new regulations regarding who can use them. Again, the answer is for the most part no: our proposals merely affect what can be placed on the market for consumers to purchase. The only exception should be restrictions governing the use of CEDs on children or vulnerable adults through contraindication labeling and the criminal law. I
机译:De Ridder,Vanneste和Focquaert解决了有关CED定义以及治疗和增强之间的区别的担忧。 1 他们在治疗增强的区别方面提出了许多问题,建议我们需要问“我们是否准备改变医疗器械指令使用的健康定义”。实际上,这里提出了三个问题。第一个是我们的建议是否需要对治疗增强区别进行强有力的表征,第二个是我们的建议是否确实如我们预期的那样涉及更改MDD中隐含的健康定义(没有明确定义),并且第三是仅将CED包含在MDD中是否会对改变“健康”或“治疗”的隐含监管概念产生实际影响。费兹和赖纳(Fitz and Reiner)广泛支持我们的建议,并赞同我们的核心主张,即。 12 。尽管如此,他们对CED用户评估CED风险的能力提出了担忧,并说“证据表明消费者处于危险中。缺乏评估与使用CED相关的风险的强大条件”(第323页)。约翰逊(Johnson),吉列(Gillett)和斯内灵(Selling)表示,最有利于我们立场的论点是基于对风险的监管评估,他们认为这应该是上市前评估中的唯一考虑因素。 14 我们建议在这里,我们各自的建议并没有看起来那么不同,因为我们建议风险应该是主要的监管问题。但是,我们与他们主张的立场背道而驰,他们认为,客观提高认知能力是可以接受的,并且与评估有关。除了对个人衡量风险能力的担忧外,Fitz和Reiner还强调了“自己动手”(DIY)用户仍然存在的问题,这些用户在从头开始构建设备时,将无法通过直接消费设备。我们同意他们的建议之一,就是通过“减少主动伤害”的其他尝试来加强我们的建议。 18 他们建议专业人士可以共同创建一个“包容性在线”社区”,可以在专业监督下收集和传播信息。如果他们对创建和维护它有足够的专家兴趣,我们对他们提出的许多建议表示同情,并支持创建一个包容性的在线社区。实际上,我们目前正在探索如何通过现有论坛(例如Reddit)来分配专家建议。 19 De Ridder,Vanneste和Focquaert提出了这样的担忧,即如果设备损坏,增强功能的社会效益可能会丧失实际上有效但受监管。关于这一点,我们强调,我们倡导的法规与禁止类似。在某种程度上,我们的建议将阻止设备投放市场,这将仅限于非常危险的设备或提出令人难以置信的要求的设备-几乎不会带来净社会收益的设备。我们模型上许多其他评论者似乎忽略的重要一点是,脑部刺激技术作为一种干预手段的有效性并不能保证声称是这种有效类型的特定令牌设备的有效性。监管部门将根据具体情况评估设备。 De Ridder,Vanneste和Focquaert提出了对资源滥用的担忧,这种滥用的立场与我们在本文中提出的立场明显不同。他们有说服力地争辩说,应该将资源用于最重要的原因,并且增强功能的优先级可能不足以保证使用有限的资源。我们同意有限的资源需要谨慎分配,但是我们的提案并不威胁这种分配:我们的提案中所禁止的设备肯定不会保证对公共资源的大量投资,并且我们的建议为资源应如何使用留有余地在允许的范围内分配。也许De Ridder和合作者以为我们主张将CED纳入医疗保健资金安排中,但这并不是我们所设想的。正如我们建议的那样,MDD范围的扩展对医疗资源的分配没有直接影响。与此相关的是,作者询问CED的法规是否要求有关谁可以使用它们的新法规。再次,答案是绝大部分:我们的建议仅影响可以投放到市场上的供消费者购买的东西。唯一的例外应该是通过禁忌标签和刑法限制对儿童或弱势成年人使用CED的限制。一世

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号