【24h】

FINDERS, KEEPERS?

机译:查找者,保持者?

获取原文

摘要

AbstractWill resource exploration firms get to keep their findings ex post, or will these be heavily taxed? To analyze this question we consider resource taxation when the government cannot commit to tax rates beyond the current period and when firms have to invest in developing new, long-lived resource deposits. In contrast with previous literature but in line with standard assumptions about rational economic behavior, taxes and exploration are both affected by anticipated decisions of future governments and firms. This dynamic hold-up problem creates a phenomenon often observed in resource producing countries: repeated cycles of exploration and taxation. In such a cycle, large findings induce a high tax which lowers exploration investment and thereby future findings, which in turn leads governments to reduce tax rates again. Such tax oscillations are more pronounced when the mining profile is more backloaded, and less pronounced in countries with more stable governments. This rich yet tractable model is the first rational expectations approach to optimal resource taxation under threat of expropriation.BackgroundTaxation of resource sectors is a large, and sometimes dominant, source of government revenue in many countries. For these governments, getting a large share of the profits without inhibiting investment is a problem of first order importance. In the simplest theory, the problem has an elegant solution: if the government could commit, the first best option would be to auction the exploration rights. This would induce firms to pay the total expected profits and explore efficiently thereafter. In practice it takes decades from first getting the right to explore until a valuable finding has been made, until a mine has been established, until extraction leads to any actual revenues and finally until the mine is exhausted. Since few governments can make credible promises on behalf of future governments, the issue of commitment becomes a real concern. In particular, a later government has incentives to tax a finding ex post. This is possibly the reason for the rare occurrence of pure auction systems when it comes to exploration.The issue of commitment is also problematic for taxation as the government today may want a low tax to induce exploration, while a later government may increase the tax in order to appropriate the profits. Rational firms and governments anticipate such future behavior. Firms will choose investment based both on current and expected future taxes. Likewise, the current government expects future reneging and hence sets the current tax taking the reaction of the firms and the future government into account. In particular, a current government may recognise that (because of expected high taxes ex post) it has to set taxes to a low level to encourage any investment at all, but then this low level of rent taxation is in turn seen as justifying later expropriation; a cycle that has been dubbed the “natural resources trap”. Such problems are very prevalent, particularly in developing countries lacking robust institutions, but also in wealthier countries. Expropriation of resource extraction firms is particularly common, for example in many Latin American countries in 2006 and 2007.ModelWe analyze this strategic interaction in a simple infinite horizon model with rational expectations. Resources are developed through costly exploration investments, but the government cannot commit to not taxing the resulting resource rents beyond a single period. In any given period, two types of mines generate resource profits: old mines discovered in the previous period and new mines discovered in the current period. In order to maximize profits from the old mines, the government would want to set a high tax, but that would harm current investment and hence profits from new mines. However, since the new mines today will, tomorrow, be taxed by the next government, today’s government has to take the future government's reaction into account, which itself depends on the reaction of the government the day after tomorrow, and so on. This means that, although the government may not directly care about the tax revenue tomorrow, it does care about how that tax affects today's firms' behavior. Hence, today's government has to consider the effect its tax has on all future taxes.The model predicts that taxes and exploration will be cyclical. This is consistent with empirical stylized facts about the nature of taxation and investment in resource-producing countries. Following anearlier large discovery, high taxes ensure the government gets a large share of the bonanza. This in turn will inhibit new investments, implying fewer mines tomorrow, and hence a lower tax as the government refocuses to ensure a sufficient level of new investments. We also study how the mining profile affects the tax. If the mining profile is backloaded, so that most of the mining profits come with a lag, then the government today knows that firms mainly care about the tax tomorrow. This makes mining investment insensitive to today's taxes, implying they are set high. This of course happens in all periods, which implies a high tax level throughout time. This inhibits investment. The backloaded mining profile dampens the tax oscillations.This paper is by no means the first to analyze resource taxation. However, to the best of our knowledge, we are the first to explicitly model the interaction between successive governments that, like firms, hold rational expectations. Also, unlike many existing papers, expropriations are not exogenous events but rather result from rational forward-looking behaviour by firms and governments.Our model is rich enough to reflect the stylized empirical fact of tax and investment cycles with agents that hold rational expectations but without the need to exogenously assume expropriations. It is also simple enough to be a logical starting point for a promising agenda of new research related to optimal taxation under imperfect commitment. For example, the model can be extended to allow for stochastic resource discoveries, changing land prospectivity and imperfect competition. It also offers many testable implications that empiricists could take to the data.
机译:抽象的 资源勘探公司会保留事后调查结果,还是对它们征收重税?为了分析这个问题,我们考虑当政府不能在当前时期内继续承诺税率,并且企业必须投资开发新的,长期的资源矿床时进行资源税。与先前的文献相反,但与合理经济行为的标准假设一致,税收和勘探都受未来政府和企业的预期决策影响。这种动态的滞留问题造成了资源生产国经常观察到的现象:勘探和税收的反复循环。在这样的周期中,大量调查结果会产生高额税收,从而降低勘探投资,从而降低未来的调查结果,进而导致政府再次降低税率。当采矿情况被更多地转移时,这种税收振荡就更加明显,而在政府更稳定的国家中,这种税收振荡就不那么明显了。这种丰富而易处理的模型是在被征收威胁下实现最优资源税的第一种理性预期方法。 背景 在许多国家,资源部门的税收是政府收入的主要来源,有时甚至占主导地位。对于这些政府而言,在不抑制投资的情况下获得大量利润是头等重要的问题。用最简单的理论来说,这个问题有一个优雅的解决方案:如果政府能够做出承诺,那么最好的选择就是拍卖勘探权。这将促使企业支付预期的总利润,并在此之后进行有效的探索。在实践中,从最初获得勘探权直到做出有价值的发现,直到建立矿山,直到开采导致任何实际收入,最后直到矿山枯竭为止,都需要数十年的时间。由于很少有政府能够代表未来的政府做出可信的承诺,因此承诺问题成为一个真正的问题。特别是,后来的政府有激励对事后征税。这可能是纯粹的拍卖系统在勘探中很少出现的原因。 承诺问题对于税收也存在问题,因为今天的政府可能希望征收低税率来进行勘探,而后来的政府可能会增加税率以挪用利润。理性的公司和政府期望这种未来的行为。企业将根据当前和预期的未来税收选择投资。同样,现任政府期望未来会改变,因此在考虑企业和未来政府的反应的情况下设定当前税率。特别是,现任政府可能认识到(由于预期事后将征收高额税款),它必须将税率设定为较低水平以完全鼓励任何投资,但随后这种低水平的租金税又被认为是以后征收的理由。 ;一个被称为“自然资源陷阱”的周期。这种问题非常普遍,特别是在缺乏健全制度的发展中国家中,在较富裕的国家中也是如此。尤其在2006年和2007年,在许多拉丁美洲国家,对资源提取公司的收购特别普遍。 模型 我们在具有理性期望的简单无限视野模型中分析这种战略互动。资源是通过昂贵的勘探投资开发的,但是政府不能承诺不对超过一个时期的资源租金征税。在任何给定时期内,两种类型的矿山都会产生资源利润:前一时期发现的旧矿山和本时期发现的新矿山。为了使旧矿的利润最大化,政府将要征收高额税收,但这会损害当前的投资,从而损害新矿的利润。但是,由于今天的新矿山明天将由下一届政府征税,因此今天的政府必须考虑到未来政府的反应,这本身取决于后天政府的反应,依此类推。这意味着,尽管政府可能不会在明天直接关注税收,但会在乎税收如何影响当今企业的行为。因此,今天的政府必须考虑其税收对所有未来税收的影响。 该模型预测税收和勘探将是周期性的。这与关于资源生产国税收和投资性质的经验性事实相吻合。在此前的大规模发现之后,高额税收确保了政府从富裕中获得了很大一部分。反过来,这将抑制新的投资,意味着明天的矿山将减少,因此,随着政府重新致力于确保足够的新投资水平,税率将降低。我们还将研究采矿状况如何影响税收。如果将矿井剖面图进行了反向加载,那么大多数挖矿利润就会出现滞后现象,那么今天的政府知道,公司明天主要关心税收。这使得矿业投资对当今的税收不敏感,这意味着它们的税率很高。当然,这在所有期间都会发生,这意味着整个时间段的税收水平很高。这抑制了投资。反向加载的采矿剖面可减轻税收波动。 本文绝不是分析资源税收的第一篇。但是,据我们所知,我们是第一个明确建立模型的历届政府之间互动关系的模型,这些政府与企业一样,都具有理性的期望。而且,与许多现有论文不同,没收不是外在事件,而是企业和政府理性前瞻性行为的结果。 我们的模型足够丰富,可以反映具有理性期望但无需外生假设征收的代理商的税收和投资周期的程式化经验事实。它也很简单,可以作为不完善承诺下与最优税收相关的新研究的有希望的议程的逻辑起点。例如,可以扩展该模型以允许随机资源发现,不断变化的土地前景和不完善的竞争。它也提供了经验主义者可以对数据采取的许多可检验的含义。

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号