首页> 外文OA文献 >Inventing Paradigms, Monopoly, Methodology, and Mythology at 'Chicago': Nutter and Stigler
【2h】

Inventing Paradigms, Monopoly, Methodology, and Mythology at 'Chicago': Nutter and Stigler

机译:在'芝加哥'发明范式,垄断,方法论和神话:Nutter和stigler

代理获取
本网站仅为用户提供外文OA文献查询和代理获取服务,本网站没有原文。下单后我们将采用程序或人工为您竭诚获取高质量的原文,但由于OA文献来源多样且变更频繁,仍可能出现获取不到、文献不完整或与标题不符等情况,如果获取不到我们将提供退款服务。请知悉。

摘要

This paper focuses on Warren Nutter’s The Extent of Enterprise Monopoly in the United States, 1899-1939. This started out as a (1949) doctoral dissertation at The University of Chicago, part of Aaron Director’s Free Market Study. Besides Director, O.H. Brownlee and Milton Friedman were closely involved with supervising it. It was published by The University of Chicago Press in 1951. In the 1950s the book was explicitly understood as belonging to the “Chicago School” (Dow and Abernathy 1963). By articulating the content, context, and reception of Nutter’s monograph, this paper discusses four larger themes. First, I introduce the importance of Kuhnian conceptions of science to the methodological and institutional understanding of economics in the development of a ‘Chicago’ school of economics. I do this in context of previously unpublished Stigler-Kuhn exchange. While Thomas Kuhn was widely read and adopted in the social sciences and humanities in the 1960s and 70s (and thereafter), I argue that at ‘Chicago,’ proto-Kuhnian language can be found going back to the 1940s; in those early days it is partly used to disparage the achievements of economic theorizing as promoted by others. A more self-congratulatory Kuhnian self-understanding of economics as a mature paradigm starts to get adopted around 1955 by George Stigler. One important new claim is that the later Kuhnian language gets adopted in part to divest ‘Chicago’ from its shared roots with Institutionalist economics. So, this paper contributes to a better understanding of the formation of a shared narrative at ‘Chicago.’ Second, I introduce contextual themes from Milton Friedman’s writings in the late 40s and 50s to help us understand the nature of realism at Chicago. Nutter’s dissertation helps in reading and illuminating Milton Friedman’s famous 1953 methodology paper in historical and intellectual context. Third, while this chapter notes some of the political ramifications of Chicago economics, my main aim is to help explain the manner in which Chicago attempted to chart a distinctive methodological course. This methodology has often been described as Marshallian with debts to the large-scale NBER studies. Rather than going over familiar territory, I call attention to the importance of proxies in Nutter’s empirical methodology. It is an unappreciated feature of the inductive, quantitative method that focused on the component structures of the economy that characterizes Chicago’s methodological outlook in this period. I show this by comparing Nutter’s dissertation to work done by Stigler, then at Columbia. We know from Stigler’s correspondence with Friedman that in this period they discussed methodological matters. What is less well known is that Friedman is explicitly credited for Stigler’s methodological insights in Stigler's Five Lectures at LSE. The fifth lecture, “Competition in the United States,” covers similar territory as Nutter’s project. Comparing the work by Stigler and Nutter sheds light on the nature of Chicago methodology as it was being developed away from foundations laid by Frank Knight and Henry Simons in the late 1940s and 1950s and opening up the door to (right wing) social engineering as exemplified by Harberger. I present my analysis through the published critical reception of both works among economists. A fourth reason to focus on Nutter’s dissertation is that it was featured in a Fortune magazine article in January 1952. So, it provides a useful entry into how politically important ‘Chicago’ research was marketed to a wider audience. This connects to issues explored by Phil Mirowski and his students, Rob van Horn and Eddie Nik-kah. So, Nutter’s dissertation can help us see how ‘sponsored’ research looks at ‘Chicago at the time. This is especially important because it has been claimed that Director’s Free Market Study group promoted a change from classically liberal views on monopoly, which condemned labor and employer monopolies, to a more pro-business stance.
机译:本文的重点是沃伦·纳特(Warren Nutter)的《美国企业垄断程度》,1899-1939年。它始于1949年在芝加哥大学的博士学位论文,是Aaron总监的自由市场研究的一部分。除了主任以外Brownlee和Milton Friedman密切参与了监督。它由芝加哥大学出版社于1951年出版。在1950年代,该书被明确理解为属于“芝加哥学派”(Dow和Abernathy,1963年)。通过阐明纳特专着的内容,背景和接受程度,本文讨论了四个更大的主题。首先,我介绍了库恩的科学观念对于“芝加哥”经济学派发展中对经济学的方法和制度理解的重要性。我是在以前未发表的Stigler-Kuhn交流中进行此操作的。尽管托马斯·库恩(Thomas Kuhn)在1960年代和70年代(及其后)在社会科学和人文科学中得到了广泛的阅读和采用,但我认为在“芝加哥”可以找到追溯到1940年代的原始库恩语。在早期,它被部分用来贬低他人推动的经济理论化的成就。乔治·斯蒂格勒(George Stigler)在1955年左右开始采用一种更为自我祝贺的科恩式经济学作为一种成熟范式的自我理解。一个重要的新主张是,后来的库恩语被部分采用,以取代芝加哥与制度主义经济学的共同根源。因此,本文有助于更好地理解“芝加哥”共享叙事的形式。其次,我介绍了40年代和50年代末弥尔顿·弗里德曼(Milton Friedman)作品的语境主题,以帮助我们理解芝加哥现实主义的本质。纳特(Nutter)的论文有助于在历史和知识背景下阅读和阐明弥尔顿·弗里德曼(Milton Friedman)1953年著名的方法论论文。第三,尽管本章指出了芝加哥经济学的一些政治影响,但我的主要目的是帮助解释芝加哥试图绘制独特的方法论路线的方式。这种方法通常被描述为Marshallian,对大型NBER研究负有责任。我没有关注熟悉的领域,而是提请注意代理在Nutter的经验方法中的重要性。这是归纳式定量方法的一个未被理解的特征,该方法侧重于表征这一时期芝加哥方法论观点的经济的构成结构。通过将Nutter的论文与Stigler(当时在哥伦比亚大学)所做的工作进行比较,可以证明这一点。从斯蒂格勒(Stigler)与弗里德曼(Friedman)的往来信件中我们知道,在此期间,他们讨论了方法论问题。鲜为人知的是,在LSE的Stigler的五次演讲中,Friedman被明确归功于Stigler的方法学见解。第五讲“美国竞争”涵盖了与纳特项目相似的领域。斯蒂格勒和纳特的工作进行比较,阐明了芝加哥方法论的本质,因为它是在1940年代和1950年代后期由弗兰克·奈特和亨利·西蒙斯奠定的基础上发展而来的,并为(右翼)社会工程学打开了大门由Harberger。我通过经济学家对这两项著作的公开批评来发表我的分析。关注Nutter论文的第四个原因是,它在1952年1月的《财富》杂志上发表。因此,它为“芝加哥”研究在政治上如何推销至更广泛的受众提供了有用的入口。这与Phil Mirowski及其学生Rob van Horn和Eddie Nik-kah探索的问题有关。因此,纳特的论文可以帮助我们了解当时“赞助”研究对“芝加哥”的看法。这一点尤为重要,因为据称主管的自由市场研究小组促进了从传统的自由主义对垄断的观点的转变,这种观点谴责了劳工和雇主的垄断,转而采用了更加亲商业的立场。

著录项

  • 作者

    Schliesser Eric;

  • 作者单位
  • 年度 2010
  • 总页数
  • 原文格式 PDF
  • 正文语种 {"code":"en","name":"English","id":9}
  • 中图分类

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
代理获取

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号