首页> 外文期刊>The American economic review >Neglected Risks: The Psychology of Financial Crises
【24h】

Neglected Risks: The Psychology of Financial Crises

机译:被忽视的风险:金融危机的心理

获取原文
获取原文并翻译 | 示例
       

摘要

Financial crises are supposed to be rare events, yet they occur quite often. According to Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), investors suffer from "this time is different" syndrome, failing to see crises coming because they do not recognize similarities among the different pre-crisis bubbles. As a result, each crisis surprises investors. Economists typically model financial crises as responses to shocks to which investors attach a low probability ex ante, but which nonetheless materialize. Such shocks (sometimes referred to as "MIT shocks"; e.g., Caballero and Simsek 2013) are consistent with rational expectations in that investors recognize that there is a small chance that the shock might occur, but they are harder to reconcile with the Reinhart Rogoff (2009) observation that crises are not that unusual. The 2008 financial crisis in the United States has deepened the challenge, by bringing up direct evidence that investors underestimated the risk of a crisis. Coval, Jurek, and Stafford (2009) show that investors underestimated the probability of mortgage defaults in pricing mortgage backed securities. Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2012) find that investors did not even contemplate the magnitude of home price declines that actually materialized. Rather than being considered unlikely, the risks appear to have been entirely neglected. We need a theory of beliefs consistent with sharp underestimates of the odds of a crisis. In this paper, we present a psychological theory of the neglect of risk and financial crises. The theory seeks to explain precisely why the probability estimates of a crisis in a boom are too low, offering a foundation of "unanticipated" shocks, and of zero probabilities attached to some states of the world by investors (Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny 2012). Our theory yields boom-bust financial crises based entirely on beliefs; we do not incorporate into the model any economic mechanisms that amplify the shocks, such as fire sales or imperfect capital markets. Our theory is based on Kahneman and Tversky's (1972) idea of representativeness, previously modeled by Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998); Gennaioli and Shleifer (2010); and Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2014). In our model, representativeness induces people to overestimate the probability of outcomes that are relatively more likely in light of recently observed data. Representativeness is intimately related to the idea of similarity: after seeing some data, people concentrate their forecasts on outcomes similar to the data observed, neglecting alternative future paths. This principle has far-reaching implications for finance. An investor observing a string of good news (Internet stocks, housing prices) views them as being generated by a favorable economic scenario. A series of good news is similar to a continuing boom. The investor then puts too much probability weight on that scenario and neglects the risk of bad outcomes. If investor expectations are elicited at this point, they look extrapolative. Observing some bad news intermixed with good news does not change the investor's mind. He views the bad news as an aberration and under-reacts. It takes a string of unfavorable news to render the bad outcome sufficiently more likely that the representative scenario changes from boom to bust. A pattern of sufficiently dramatic or continuing bad news is similar to the low payoff state, leading to a change in the underlying beliefs. Previously ignored bad news is remembered, leading to a sharp rise in the perceived probability of a crisis and a collapse of prices. The investor now overreacts to the bad news, especially if the true probability of the low state remains low. The possibility of black swans is initially ignored, but ultimately turns into an overstated fear that leads to a self-generating crisis. In contrast to rational expectations, the model yields purely belief-driven boom bust cycles.
机译:金融危机本来应该是罕见的事件,但是却经常发生。根据Reinhart和Rogoff(2009)的观点,投资者遭受“这次不同了”的综合症,未能看到危机的来临,因为他们没有意识到危机前不同泡沫之间的相似之处。结果,每次危机都使投资者感到惊讶。经济学家通常将金融危机模型化为对投资者事前事半功倍的震荡的反应,但这种震荡仍在发生。这样的冲击(有时称为“ MIT冲击”;例如,Caballero和Simsek 2013)与理性预期是一致的,因为投资者认识到发生冲击的可能性很小,但很难与莱因哈特·罗格夫调和。 (2009年)的观察发现,危机并不是那么罕见。通过提供直接证据表明投资者低估了危机的风险,2008年美国的金融危机加剧了挑战。 Coval,Jurek和Stafford(2009)指出,投资者在对抵押贷款支持证券进行定价时低估了抵押贷款违约的可能性。富特,杰拉迪和威伦(Foote,Gerardi和Willen,2012年)发现,投资者甚至没有考虑到实际出现的房价下跌幅度。与其被认为是不可能的,风险似乎已被完全忽略。我们需要一种与低估危机几率一致的信念理论。在本文中,我们提出了一种忽视风险和金融危机的心理学理论。该理论试图精确解释为什么繁荣时期危机的概率估计值太低,从而为“意外”冲击和投资者在世界某些州附加的零概率奠定了基础(Gennaioli,Shleifer和Vishny,2012年)。 )。我们的理论完全基于信念产生了繁荣与萧条的金融危机。我们没有在模型中纳入任何会加剧冲击的经济机制,例如售火或不完善的资本市场。我们的理论基于Kahneman和Tversky(1972)的代表性思想,该思想先前由Barberis,Shleifer和Vishny(1998)建模。根纳利奥利和什列弗(2010)以及Bordalo,Gennaioli和Shleifer(2014)。在我们的模型中,根据最近观察到的数据,代表性导致人们高估了可能性更高的结果。代表性与相似性概念密切相关:看到一些数据后,人们将预测集中在与观察到的数据相似的结果上,而忽略了未来的替代路径。这一原则对金融具有深远的影响。观察到一系列好消息(互联网股票,住房价格)的投资者将其视为有利的经济情景所产生。一系列的好消息类似于持续的繁荣。然后,投资者对这种情况施加了过多的概率权重,而忽略了不良结果的风险。如果在这一点上引起投资者的期望,它们看起来就是外推的。观察一些坏消息与好消息混杂在一起并不会改变投资者的想法。他认为坏消息是一种畸变和反应不足。一连串的不利消息使不良结果更有可能使代表性的情况从繁荣转为萧条。足够剧烈或持续的坏消息的模式类似于低回报状态,从而导致基本信念的变化。记住了以前忽略的坏消息,导致人们认为危机和价格暴跌的可能性急剧上升。投资者现在对坏消息反应过度,尤其是在低位状态的真实可能性仍然很低的情况下。黑天鹅的可能性最初被忽略,但最终变成了夸大的恐惧,导致了自发的危机。与理性预期相反,该模型产生的纯粹是信念驱动的繁荣萧条周期。

著录项

  • 来源
    《The American economic review》 |2015年第5期|310-314|共5页
  • 作者单位

    Department of Finance, Universita Bocconi, Via Roentgen 1, Milan, Italy;

    Economics Department, Harvard University, Littauer Center, 1805 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138;

    Chicago Booth, University of Chicago, 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue, Chicago. IL 60637;

  • 收录信息 美国《科学引文索引》(SCI);美国《化学文摘》(CA);
  • 原文格式 PDF
  • 正文语种 eng
  • 中图分类
  • 关键词

  • 入库时间 2022-08-17 23:26:46

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号