首页> 外文学位 >Peasants, productivity and profit in the open fields of England: A study of economic and social development.
【24h】

Peasants, productivity and profit in the open fields of England: A study of economic and social development.

机译:英格兰开放地区的农民,生产率和利润:经济和社会发展研究。

获取原文
获取原文并翻译 | 示例

摘要

England's pre-industrial development, and that of western Europe in general, is traditionally approached by historians within a Malthusian framework of analysis, which has been shaped largely by neoclassical and Marxist economic models. The amount of food produced by each full-time agricultural worker, that is, labour productivity, is held to be the primary engine of growth. Historians hold that the middle ages were characterized by widespread dire poverty and economic stagnation, based on the belief that the amount of food produced by each worker was very low. By the early fourteenth century, they believe that it did not even suffice to feed the existing populace. Medieval social and economic institutions---serfdom and the open fields---precluded socioeconomic progress, by lowering labour productivity in the huge peasant sector as well as on the demesne, the lord's share of the open fields.; The direct measurement of English labour productivity rates in this thesis, c. 1280 to 1415, which are the first ever produced for any country in medieval Europe, were rendered possible through the construction of a methodology that allowed the exploitation of manorial account rolls. The approach taken was a comparative analysis of nine villages which were reconstructed at the local level and studied in their socioeconomic contexts.; The labour productivity rates in these peasant-controlled open fields surpassed those for English agricultural workers in enclosed fields of the mid-nineteenth century. These findings have a number of implications, not simply for the middle ages, but also for the early modern period. For example, support cannot be found for the notion of an Agricultural Revolution, currently defined as a rise in labour productivity, which served as a necessary precursor to the Industrial Revolution. Food surplus was quite high and there was no danger of a Malthusian crisis in the pre-1350 period. And if Malthus does not apply in this period, with its high population levels, he certainly is not applicable to any centuries that followed, with their lower population levels.; Many historians argue that only with the dismantling of serfdom and the open fields was economic progress achieved. Unlike eastern European serfdom, analysis of labour rents on these English manors indicates that the manor was not a labour-based system in the west. As for the medieval open fields, they were not an impetus to development but appear to have served as the cornerstone for peasant economic progress. New economic models are offered for both institutions.; This thesis demonstrated that development did not occur in medieval and early modern England as historians have supposed, and by extension, perhaps did not necessarily proceed as assumed elsewhere in time and place. Instead, a comparative analysis of labour productivity rates between the pre- and post-1350 periods suggests an alternative paradigm for medieval development, one that is perhaps applicable for the entire pre-industrial period: income distribution in the huge peasant sector might have shaped socioeconomic trends. It seems possible that growth was fostered by a more equitable division of wealth in the pre-1350 period. More research is required to substantiate this hypothesis but at the very least, trends in the real value of output per worker and per acre, which were higher before 1350 than in the decades that followed, indicate that the first half of the century was the primary period of economic growth and was characterized by higher living standards than the half-century that followed. Historians have usually held that the converse was the case.
机译:历史学家传统上是在马尔萨斯分析框架内,由历史学家来研究英格兰的工业前发展,以及整个西欧的工业发展,而该框架在很大程度上是由新古典主义和马克思主义的经济模型所决定的。每个专职农业工人生产的食物量,即劳动生产率,被认为是增长的主要动力。历史学家认为,中世纪的特点是普遍的严重贫困和经济停滞,其原因是人们相信每个工人生产的食物数量很少。到了十四世纪初,他们认为这还不足以养活现有的平民。中世纪的社会和经济机构-农奴制和空地-降低了巨大的农民部门以及德米内的劳动生产率,从而阻碍了社会经济的进步。本文直接测量了英国劳动生产率。 1280年至1415年,这是中世纪欧洲任何国家/地区首次生产的产品,通过构建允许利用房地产账册的方法,使之成为可能。采取的方法是对九个村庄进行比较分析,这些村庄在地方一级进行了重建,并在其社会经济背景下进行了研究。在十九世纪中叶,这些农民控制的空地的劳动生产率超过了英国农业工人的劳动生产率。这些发现不仅对中世纪有影响,而且对现代早期也有很多影响。例如,无法找到对农业革命的概念的支持,农业革命目前被定义为劳动生产率的提高,是工业革命的必要先兆。粮食过剩很高,在1350年以前没有发生马尔萨斯危机的危险。而且,如果马尔萨斯(Mathus)在这段时期内人口数量很高,因此不适用,那么他肯定不适用于随后几个世纪以来人口数量较低的世纪。许多历史学家认为,只有解散农奴制和开阔土地,才能实现经济进步。与东欧农奴制不同,对这些英国庄园的租金进行的分析表明,该庄园在西方不是基于劳动力的制度。至于中世纪的旷野,它们并不是发展的动力,但似乎已成为农民经济发展的基石。这两个机构都提供了新的经济模式。该论文表明,发展并没有像历史学家所认为的那样在中世纪和近代早期的英国发生,并且从广义上讲,发展并不一定像其他时间和地点那样进行。取而代之的是,对1350年之前和之后时期之间劳动生产率的比较分析提出了中世纪发展的另一种范式,该范式可能适用于整个工业化前时期:庞大的农民部门的收入分配可能已经塑造了社会经济趋势。在1350年之前的时期,财富分配似乎更加公平,从而促进了增长。需要更多的研究来证实这一假设,但至少,每名工人和每英亩的实际产出价值的趋势在1350年之前高于随后的几十年,表明本世纪上半叶是主要的经济增长时期,其特点是生活水平高于随后的半个世纪。历史学家通常认为情况恰恰相反。

著录项

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号