首页> 外文学位 >Essays on market structure and price in the Korean retail gasoline market.
【24h】

Essays on market structure and price in the Korean retail gasoline market.

机译:关于韩国​​零售汽油市场的市场结构和价格的文章。

获取原文
获取原文并翻译 | 示例

摘要

This study empirically examines the relationship between market structure and prices in the Korean retail gasoline market. Korea has experienced big changes in the number of gas stations. For example, nationally the number of gas stations increased 24.9% from 10,406 in 2001 to 13,003 in 2010, but in Seoul the number of stations dropped 24.9% from 816 in 2001 to 613 in 2013.;In the literature, the empirical research about the relationship between the market structure and prices in the retail gasoline market has been done in two ways. First, studies with regression models have mainly focused on finding market structure as the determinant of retail prices. Second, a few studies with structural models have assessed the impacts of mergers on prices. However, previous studies had some limitations: (1) most regression analyses did not evaluate the long-term impact because they used cross-sectional data or short-term panel data; more importantly, they did not successfully correct an endogeneity problem because they used a controversial instrumental variable; (2) because quantity data at the station level were rarely accessible, it was not easy to utilize a structural model.;In Chapter 1, I employ monthly data between January 2003 and December 2011 from seven big cities in Korea to estimate the effects of station density on average retail prices and average sales per station. Instead of population density, which has been commonly used in previous studies, I use the density of diesel cars as the new instrumental variable. First, the correlation between station density and the new instrument is obviously expected to be higher than the correlation between station density and population density, because demand for stations depends on the number of cars rather than the number of people. Second, population density may well represent demand for gasoline and therefore have a direct impact on the retail price. Meanwhile, the density of diesel cars satisfies instrument exogeneity because it is not a determinant of gasoline price.;Estimation results yield the following findings. First, regarding a price equation, an OLS estimate of station density is negative but statistically insignificant. However, an IV estimate of station density is negative and statistically significant. The results demonstrate that the OLS estimate underestimates the impact of station density on prices. The IV estimation results show that a 10% increase in the number of stations per square kilometer is associated with a 0.68-0.95% decrease in retail prices. Second, regarding a sales equation, the OLS and IV coefficient estimates of station density are negative, statistically significant and very similar in magnitude. A 10% increase in station density is associated with a 4.2-5.9% decrease in station sales. These findings also imply that the number of stations is an endogenous variable with respect to price, but not with respect to sales. This is the same as the result of Sen and Townley (2010), who examined the retail gasoline industry in Canada.;In Chapter 2, with June 2009 data from 270 gas stations located above the Han River in Seoul, Korea, I use a structural model and conduct counterfactual experiments to estimate the effects of market structure on prices and welfare. I estimate the model without quantity data from the gas stations by employing the idea of Thomadsen (2005), while previous studies used sales data by directly following the work of Berry et al. (1995). In general, it is difficult to obtain quantity data from gas stations because they keep them secret. Also, data richness allows me to introduce different contractual forms between refiners and stations in the supply model, while previous studies assumed because of data limitations that there was only one type of vertical relationship.;The counterfactual experiments yield the following results. First, although the change to company-owned GS (or HD) stations increases their prices, the prices of company-owned SK stations decrease, decreasing average price. Consumer welfare also decreases because the base utility of GS (HD) stations is smaller than that of SK stations. Second, the change to non-company-owned SK stations decreases the average price because the decreasing effects of ownership changes on prices outweighs the increasing effects of change in vertical contracts on marginal costs, which increases consumer welfare. Third, the change to non-company-owned S-Oil stations greatly lowers the average price mainly because the refiner's wholesale price is the lowest among all refiners. Finally, the exit of stations causes an increase in average price.;The above analysis implies that drop in the number of gas stations leads to very different effects on price and welfare, depending on how brand and contractual form change. Therefore, policies to affect market structure should be developed and implemented with caution because they may have unanticipated effects. (Abstract shortened by UMI.).
机译:这项研究以实证检验了韩国零售汽油市场中市场结构与价格之间的关系。韩国的加油站数量发生了巨大变化。例如,全国加油站数量从2001年的10406个增加到2010年的13003个,增长了24.9%,但在首尔,加油站的数量从2001年的816个下降到2013年的613个,下降了24.9%;在文献中,关于加油站的经验研究零售汽油市场的市场结构和价格之间的关系已通过两种方式完成。首先,回归模型的研究主要集中在寻找市场结构作为零售价格的决定因素。其次,一些关于结构模型的研究评估了合并对价格的影响。但是,先前的研究存在一些局限性:(1)大多数回归分析未评估长期影响,因为它们使用了横截面数据或短期面板数据;更重要的是,由于使用了有争议的工具变量,他们未能成功纠正内生性问题。 (2)由于很少获得站级的数量数据,因此使用结构模型并不容易。在第一章中,我使用了韩​​国7个大城市在2003年1月至2011年12月之间的月度数据来估算平均零售价格和平均每站销售量得出的站点密度。代替以前的研究中通常使用的人口密度,我使用柴油车的密度作为新的工具变量。首先,显然,车站密度与新仪器之间的相关性要高于车站密度与人口密度之间的相关性,因为对车站的需求取决于汽车的数量而不是人数。其次,人口密度很可能代表对汽油的需求,因此直接影响零售价格。同时,柴油汽车的密度满足了仪器的外生性,因为它不是汽油价格的决定因素。估计结果得出以下发现。首先,关于价格等式,站点密度的OLS估计为负,但在统计上不重要。但是,站点密度的IV估计为负且具有统计意义。结果表明,OLS估计低估了站点密度对价格的影响。 IV估算结果表明,每平方公里车站数量增加10%,零售价格下降0.68-0.95%。其次,关于销售方程式,站点密度的OLS和IV系数估计为负,具有统计意义,并且幅度非常相似。站点密度增加10%,站点销售减少4.2-5.9%。这些发现还暗示,车站数量是价格的内生变量,而不是销量的内生变量。这与Sen和Townley(2010)的研究结果相同,后者研究了加拿大的零售汽油行业。在第二章中,利用2009年6月来自韩国汉城汉江上方270个加油站的数据,我使用了结构模型并进行反事实实验,以估算市场结构对价格和福利的影响。我采用Thomadsen(2005)的想法估算了没有加油站数量数据的模型,而以前的研究则直接遵循Berry等人的工作来使用销售数据。 (1995)。通常,很难从加油站获取数量数据,因为它们会将它们保密。同样,数据丰富性使我能够在供应模型中的炼油厂和加油站之间引入不同的合同形式,而以前的研究则由于数据限制而假定只有一种垂直关系。反事实实验得出以下结果。首先,尽管更改为公司拥有的GS(或HD)站的价格会增加,但公司拥有的SK站的价格会下降,从而降低平均价格。由于GS(HD)站的基本效用小于SK站的基本效用,因此消费者福利也下降了。第二,非公司所有的SK站的变更降低了平均价格,因为所有权变更对价格的降低影响大于垂直合同变更对边际成本的增加影响,这增加了消费者的福利。第三,改用非公司所有的S-Oil加油站会大大降低平均价格,这主要是因为炼油厂的批发价在所有炼油厂中是最低的。最后,加油站的退出会导致平均价格上涨。以上分析表明,加油站数量的减少对价格和福利产生了截然不同的影响,具体取决于品牌和合同形式的变化。因此,应谨慎制定和执行影响市场结构的政策,因为它们可能会产生意想不到的影响。 (摘要由UMI缩短。)。

著录项

  • 作者

    Kim, Moonsik.;

  • 作者单位

    University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.;

  • 授予单位 University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.;
  • 学科 Economic theory.;Commerce-Business.;Finance.
  • 学位 Ph.D.
  • 年度 2014
  • 页码 111 p.
  • 总页数 111
  • 原文格式 PDF
  • 正文语种 eng
  • 中图分类
  • 关键词

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 中文文献
  • 专利
获取原文

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号