首页> 外文OA文献 >Identifying, estimating and correcting the biases in WTO rules on public stocks: a proposal for the post-Bali food security agenda
【2h】

Identifying, estimating and correcting the biases in WTO rules on public stocks: a proposal for the post-Bali food security agenda

机译:识别,估计和纠正世贸组织关于公共储备的规则中的偏见:后巴厘岛粮食安全议程的提案

摘要

In this paper, we analyze the WTO rules that specify how to estimate the subsidy provided to farmers by public stocks. We identify three biases in these rules: - Bias B1, resulting from using a fixed past unit value of import or export as external reference price, instead of the current price cost of imports or exports. - Bias B2, resulting from using the procurement price of the public stock instead of the price prevailing on the domestic market to estimate the price support received by the farmers who sell their production on the domestic market. - Bias B3, resulting from using the national production instead of the marketed share of national production, by this way ignoring farmer self-consumption. The effect of these three biases on the estimated subsidy varies with the country but, on average, WTO rules lead to overestimate the subsidy by a factor 2 to more than 300, depending on the modalities of public stock interventions and other parameters. This means that in the most favorable scenarios, the estimated subsidy is (on average) twice the real subsidy. The effect of these biases on country compliance proves to be huge: many countries have an estimated subsidy above their maximum allowed level (even with very light public stock interventions), just because the subsidy provided by public stocks is overestimated by WTO rules. This result challenges the widespread idea that almost all countries comply with WTO rules on public stocks. We also test the effect of correcting only some of the biases. It appears that doing this would not allow eliminating the biases in country compliance. An implication of this is that expressing the fixed external reference price (FERP) in US dollar, correcting it with the country inflation rate or replacing it by the average unit value of imports or exports over the last five years (as proposed by several experts and WTO Members) would not be enough to remove the bias on country compliance. There is therefore a need to correct all the three biases, what can be done in a rather simple way, as is shown at the end of the paper.
机译:在本文中,我们分析了WTO规则,这些规则指定了如何估算公共库存提供给农民的补贴。我们在这些规则中确定了三个偏差:-偏差B1,这是由于使用固定的进口或出口过去单位价值作为外部参考价格,而不是使用当前的进口或出口价格成本造成的。 -偏差B2,是通过使用公共股票的采购价格而不是国内市场上的现行价格来估算在国内市场上出售产品的农民所获得的价格支持。 -偏差B3,是由于使用国民生产而不是国民生产的市场份额而导致的,因此忽略了农民的自我消费。这三种偏差对估计的补贴的影响因国家而异,但平均而言,WTO规则会导致将补贴高估2到300倍以上,具体取决于公共股票干预措施的方式和其他参数。这意味着在最有利的情况下,估计的补贴(平均)是实际补贴的两倍。这些偏见对国家合规的影响被证明是巨大的:许多国家的补贴估计都超过了其最大允许水平(即使在非常少量的公共储备干预下),只是因为WTO规则高估了公共储备提供的补贴。这一结果挑战了这样一种普遍观念,即几乎所有国家都遵守WTO关于公共库存的规定。我们还测试了仅纠正某些偏差的效果。看来这样做并不能消除国家合规方面的偏见。这暗示着用美元表示固定的外部参考价格(FERP),用国家的通货膨胀率对其进行校正,或者用过去五年中进出口的平均单位价值代替(如一些专家和专家所建议的那样)。 WTO成员)不足以消除对国家合规性的偏见。因此,有必要校正所有三个偏差,这可以用一种非常简单的方式完成,如本文结尾所示。

著录项

  • 作者

    Galtier Franck;

  • 作者单位
  • 年度 2015
  • 总页数
  • 原文格式 PDF
  • 正文语种 en
  • 中图分类

相似文献

  • 外文文献
  • 专利

客服邮箱:kefu@zhangqiaokeyan.com

京公网安备:11010802029741号 ICP备案号:京ICP备15016152号-6 六维联合信息科技 (北京) 有限公司©版权所有
  • 客服微信

  • 服务号